Carry trade strategies explained by structure of international trade

15.October 2015

#5 – FX Carry Trade

Authors: Ready, Roussanov, Ward

Title: Commodity Trade and the Carry Trade: A Tale of Two Countries

Link: http://jacobslevycenter.wharton.upenn.edu/wp-content/uploads/2015/05/Commodity-Trade-and-the-Carry-Trade-4.3.15.pdf

Abstract:

Persistent differences in interest rates across countries account for much of the profitability of currency carry trade strategies.  The high-interest rate "investment" currencies tend to be "commodity currencies,"  while low interest rate "funding" currencies tend to belong to countries that export finished goods and import most of their commodities.  We develop a general equilibrium model of international trade and currency pricing in which countries have an advantage in producing either basic input goods or final consumable goods. The model predicts that commodity-producing countries are insulated from global productivity shocks through a combination of trade frictions and domestic production, which forces the final goods producers to absorb the shocks.  As a result, the commodity country currency is risky as it tends to depreciate in bad times, yet has higher interest rates on average due to lower precautionary demand, compared to the final-good producer.  The carry trade risk premium increases in the degree of specialization, and the real exchange rate tracks relative technological productivity of the two countries.  The model's predictions are strongly supported in the data.

Notable quotations from the academic research paper:

"A currency carry trade is a strategy that goes long high interest rate currencies and short low interest rate currencies. A typical carry trade involves buying the Australian dollar, which for much of the last three decades earned a high interest rate, and funding the position with borrowing in the Japanese yen, thus paying an extremely low rate on the short leg. Such a strategy earns positive expected returns on average, and exhibits high Sharpe ratios despite its substantial volatility.  In the absence of arbitrage this implies that the marginal utility of an investor whose consumption basket is denominated in yen is more volatile than that of an Australian consumer. Are there fundamental economic di erences between countries that could give rise to such a heterogeneity in risk?

One  source  of  di erences  across  countries  is  the  composition  of  their  trade. Countries that specialize in exporting basic commodities, such as Australia or New Zealand, tend to have high interest rates.  Conversely, countries that import most of the basic input goods and  export  fi nished  consumption  goods,  such  as  Japan  or  Switzerland,  have  low  interest rates on average.  These diff erences in interest rates do not translate into the depreciation of
"commodity currencies" on average; rather, they constitute positive average returns, giving rise  to  a  carry  trade-type  strategy. In  this  paper  we  develop  a  theoretical  model  of  this phenomenon, document that this empirical pattern is systematic and robust over the recent time period, and provide additional evidence in support of the model's predictions for the dynamics of carry trade strategies.

We show that the diff erences in average interest rates and risk exposures between countries  that  are  net  importers  of  basic  commodities  and  commodity-exporting  countries can be explained by appealing to a natural economic mechanism:  trade costs.

We model trade costs by considering a simple model of the shipping industry.  At any time the cost of transporting  a  unit  of  good  from  one  country  to  the  other  depends  on  the  aggregate  shipping capacity available.  While the capacity of the shipping sector adjusts over time to match the demand for transporting  goods between countries,  it  does so slowly,  due to  gestation  lags in the shipbuilding industry.  In order to capture this intuition we assume marginal costs of shipping an extra unit of good is increasing – i.e., trade costs in our model are convex.  Convex shipping costs imply that the sensitivity of the commodity country to world productivity shocks is lower than that of the country that specializes in producing the final consumption good, simply because it is costlier to deliver an extra unit of the consumption good to the commodity  country  in  good  times,  but  cheaper  in  bad  times.   Therefore,  under  complete financial markets, the commodity country's consumption is smoother than it would be in the absence of trade frictions, and, conversely, the commodity importer's consumption is riskier. Since the commodity country faces less consumption risk, it has a lower precautionary saving demand and, consequently, a higher interest rate on average, compared to the country producing manufactured goods.  Since the commodity currency is risky – it depreciates in bad times – it commands a risk premium.  Therefore, the interest rate di fferential is not off set on average by exchange rate movements, giving rise to a carry trade.

We show empirically that sorting currencies into portfolios based on net exports of fi nished (manufactured) goods or basic commodities generates a substantial spread in average excess returns, which subsumes the unconditional (but not conditional) carry trade documented by Lustig,  Roussanov,  and  Verdelhan  (2011).   Further,  we  show  that  aggregate  consumption of  commodity  countries  is  less  risky  than  that  of  finished  goods  producers,  as  our  model predicts"


Are you looking for more strategies to read about? Check http://quantpedia.com/Screener

Do you want to see performance of trading systems we described? Check http://quantpedia.com/Chart/Performance

Do you want to know more about us? Check http://quantpedia.com/Home/About

Continue reading

Optimization of Equity Momentum

7.October 2015

#14 – Momentum Effect in Stocks

Authors: van Oord

Title: Optimization of Equity Momentum: (How) Does it Work?

Link: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2653680
 

Abstract:

Standard mean-variance optimized momentum outperforms the traditional equally weighted momentum strategy if the expected return vector used reflects momentum's top and bottom only characteristic. This top and bottom only characteristic is the phenomenon that only the stocks in the top decile of momentum's ranking outperform and that only stocks in the bottom decile underperform, while all stocks in the intermediate deciles of the ranking have similar performance. If the optimization does not take this phenomenon into account the portfolio is also long the deciles 2 to 5 and short the deciles 6 to 9, while all these positions thus do not add anything to the return of the strategy. A new simplified bootstrapping methodology shows that the Sharpe-ratio of 52.8 percent of the optimized portfolio is significantly higher (p-value of 0.006) than the Sharpe-ratio of 29.3 percent for traditional equally weighted momentum. The optimized portfolio also exhibit less time-varying equity risk factor return exposures than traditional momentum and as such have more stable returns over the business cycle and have smaller drawdowns.

Notable quotations from the academic research paper:

"The traditional momentum strategy ranks stocks on their recent 3 to 12 months average returns, skips one month to overcome short-term return reversals and then buys the stocks in the top decile of the ranking and short-sells the stocks in the bottom decile of this ranking. Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) show that this traditional momentum strategy has a signi cant positive average return. Using standard mean-variance optimization with these recent average stock returns as input for the expected returns results in a signi cantly higher Sharpe-ratio than the traditional momentum strategy if the expected returns reflect momentum's top and bottom only characteristic.

We show that the momentum is a top and bottom only strategy. Given momentum's signi cant outperformance of the top decile over the bottom decile of its ranking on the stocks' recent performance one would expect that stocks in the second decile would also outperform stocks in the ninth decile. This is, however, not the case: all stocks in the second to ninth decile have similar performance. When using the recent stocks' performances as expected returns
in the optimization thus results in long positions in the second to fth decile and short positions in the sixth to ninth deciles. These long-short positions do not add to the performance as they have similar returns. In fact, these positions decrease momentum's performance as they reduce the weights in the top and bottom decile that do outperfom each other and do add to the performance."


Are you looking for more strategies to read about? Check http://quantpedia.com/Screener

Do you want to see performance of trading systems we described? Check http://quantpedia.com/Chart/Performance

Do you want to know more about us? Check http://quantpedia.com/Home/About

Continue reading

How general market conditions affect industry/sector momentum ?

1.October 2015

#3 – Sector Momentum – Rotational System

Authors: Huhn

Title: Industry Momentum: The Role of Time-Varying Factor Exposures and Market Conditions

Link: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2650378

Abstract:

This paper focuses on momentum strategies based on recent and intermediate past returns of U.S. industry portfolios. Our empirical analysis shows that strategies based on intermediate past returns yield higher mean returns. Moreover, strategies involving both return specifications exhibit time-varying factor exposures, especially the Fama and French (2015) five-factor model. After risk-adjusting for these dynamic exposures, the profitability of industry momentum strategies diminishes and becomes insignificant for strategies based on recent past returns. However, most strategies built on intermediate past returns remain profitable and highly significant. Further analyses reveal that industry momentum strategies are disrupted by periods of strong negative risk-adjusted returns. These so-called momentum crashes seem to be driven by specific market conditions. We find that industry momentum strategies are related to market states and to the business cycle. However, there is no clear evidence that industry momentum can be linked to market volatility or sentiment.

Notable quotations from the academic research paper:

"Our empirical results indicate that momentum strategies based on industry portfolios are profitable within the U.S. Moreover, in line with Novy-Marx (2012), strategies based on intermediate past returns from months twelve to seven exhibit higher returns than strategies based on recent past returns from months six to two prior to portfolio formation. However, when using alternative formation periods for intermediate past returns, our results do not support the hypothesis of momentum being an “echo” in returns.

Our paper seeks to determine whether industry momentum strategies based on recent and intermediate past returns exhibit time-varying factor exposures in the U.S. We therefore apply different factor models and examine which model best explains industry momentum returns. Our results indicate that for both return specifications, industry momentum strategies exhibit time-varying factor exposures, especially using the FF (2015) five-factor model. Hedging these time-varying factor exposures diminishes the outperformance of industry momentum strategies.

To the best of our knowledge, no study so far has analyzed the relation between market conditions and industry momentum strategies based on both recent and intermediate past returns. Giving additional scrutiny to this research area, we examine whether industry momentum strategies are also disrupted by periods of strong negative returns. Our empirical analyses reveal that industry momentum strategies based on both return specifications experience periods with large negative risk-adjusted returns. Moreover, these so-called momentum crashes seem to be driven by specific market conditions. We find that industry momentum strategies are related to market states and are thus only profitable following “UP”-markets. We do not find positive and significant risk-adjusted returns following “DOWN”-markets, regardless of market transitions. These results support behavioral explanations as the source of the profitability of industry momentum strategies. Dividing both recessions and expansions into two halves, our results indicate that most strategies exhibit positive and significant risk-adjusted returns only during the second half of an expansion. Finally, our findings do not support the notion that industry momentum strategies are related to market volatility or investor sentiment."


Are you looking for more strategies to read about? Check http://quantpedia.com/Screener

Do you want to see performance of trading systems we described? Check http://quantpedia.com/Chart/Performance

Do you want to know more about us? Check http://quantpedia.com/Home/About

Continue reading

New academic paper analyses #38 – Accrual Anomaly

22.September 2015

#38 – Accrual Anomaly

Authors: Patatoukas

Title: Asymmetrically Timely Loss Recognition and the Accrual Anomaly

Link: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2653979

Abstract:

Conditionally conservative accounting practices mandate the more timely recognition of losses relative to gains through transitory negative accrual items. A direct implication of asymmetrically timely loss recognition is asymmetry in the persistence of accruals depending on whether the firm experiences a gain or a loss in the current year: accruals should be less persistent for loss years relative to profit years. If investors naively fixate on total earnings, however, conditional conservatism would imply that investors will tend to overestimate the persistence of accruals especially in loss years. Consistent with naïve earnings fixation, I find that Sloan’s (1996) accrual anomaly, i.e., the negative association between accruals and future abnormal stock returns, is more pronounced for loss firms relative to profit firms. The evidence is relevant for understanding the origins of the accrual anomaly and highlights that inferences with respect to the pricing of accruals can be affected by pooling loss firms with profit firms.

Notable quotations from the academic research paper:

"Separating firms based on the sign of reported earnings, I find that although the accrual anomaly extends across profit and loss firms, it appears to be stronger for loss firms. The average hedge return from buying/selling low/high accrual loss firms is 16.99 percent, while the hedge return from buying/selling low/high accrual profit firms is 5.82 percent. Evidence of accrual mispricing further increases when I separate loss firms experiencing negative contemporaneous abnormal returns (roughly 72 percent of all loss firms), with the hedge return from buying/selling low/high accrual loss firms rising to 21.77 percent.

Overall, the evidence suggests that the subsample of loss firms is more susceptible to accruals mispricing, which is consistent with the prediction that investors naively fixate on total earnings and, therefore, tend to overestimate the persistence of accruals especially in loss years. The evidence presented here also highlights that inferences regarding variation in the accrual anomaly across profit and loss firms are sensitive to the measurement of the accrual component of earnings."


Are you looking for more strategies to read about? Check http://quantpedia.com/Screener

Do you want to see performance of trading systems we described? Check http://quantpedia.com/Chart/Performance

Do you want to know more about us? Check http://quantpedia.com/Home/About

Continue reading

Order Flow explains FX Carry Trade Strategies

15.September 2015

#5 – FX Carry Trade

Authors: Breedon, Rime, Vitale

Title: Carry Trades, Order Flow and the Forward Bias Puzzle

Link: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2643531

Abstract:

We investigate the relation between foreign exchange (FX) order flow and the forward bias. We outline a decomposition of the forward bias according to which a negative correlation between interest rate differentials and order flow creates a time-varying risk premium consistent with that bias. Using ten years of data on FX order flow we find that more than half of the forward bias is accounted for by order flow — with the rest being explained by expectational errors. We also find that carry trading increases currency-crash risk in that order flow generates negative skewness in FX returns.

Notable quotations from the academic research paper:

Continue reading

A way to an improved Size and Value Factors

8.September 2015

#25 – Small Capitalization Stocks Premium Anomaly
#26 – Value (Book-to-Market) Anomaly

Authors: Lambert, Fays, Hubner

Title: Size and Value Matter, But Not the Way You Thought

Link: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2647298

Abstract:

Fama and French factors do not reliably estimate the size and book-to-market effects. We demonstrate inconsistent pricing of those factors in the US stock market. We replace Fama and French’s independent rankings with the conditional ones introduced by Lambert and Hübner (2013). Controlling ex-ante for noise in the estimation procedure, we have been able to highlight a much stronger book-to-market and size effects than have conventionally been documented similar to Asness et al. (2015). As a significant related outcome, the alternative risk factors have been found to deliver less specification errors when used to price investment portfolios.

Notable quotations from the academic research paper:

Continue reading

Subscribe for Newsletter

Be first to know, when we publish new content


    logo
    The Encyclopedia of Quantitative Trading Strategies

    Log in

    MORE INFO
    We boasts a total prize pool of $15,000
    Gain a Share of a Total Prize Pool of $15.000
    MORE INFO
    $15.000
    Gain a Share of a Total Prize Pool